Hawk Helicopter
Fed Chairman Bernake is famous for once having given a speech in which he trumpeted the Fed’s ability to combat deflation by creating money – if necessary, by dropping it from a helicopter. The image of Old Ben piloting a chopper, raining dollars on a world fertile for price growth, has stuck in the minds of many inflation hawks and left them with the impression that the Chairman is likely to be relatively soft on inflation. But when we look at his famous statement in context and apply the logic of central banking, it becomes clear that this conventional interpretation is not just incorrect but diametrically opposite to the statement’s true implication.
First we have to recognize that there is a consensus that deflation is bad. It is a matter of dispute just how bad deflation is. But it is fair to say that those who regard deflation as a potentially healthy process are a small minority. To many, deflation conjures up images of the early 1930s, probably the most unpleasant period in the history of capitalism. There is also dispute – and this is where Bernanke’s speech weighs in – about how hard it would be to end a deflation if such a thing were to materialize. The example of Japan suggests a rather pessimistic prognosis, but Bernanke’s speech makes clear that he thinks more effective anti-deflation policies would have succeeded much sooner in Japan.
As a central banker, one is faced constantly with the problem of balancing risks. The biggest risks, I think most would agree, are, on the one side, deflation, and, on the other side, excessive inflation. The problems associated with high inflation are well known. From a central banker’s point of view, it isn’t really the end of the world, because it is generally acknowledged to be curable. The cure, however, is painful and politically difficult, so most central bankers make diligent efforts to provide more than an ounce of prevention. Deflation, on the other hand, is not generally acknowledged to be curable, so some central bankers might regard it as the end of the world. Anyone who does regard deflation as the end of the world is likely to tilt the balance of risks toward inflation.
Bernanke, it should be abundantly clear, is not such a central banker. Bernanke thinks deflation is a solvable problem, just like inflation, and the solution to the deflation problem is a lot less painful than the solution to the inflation problem. Accordingly, Bernanke is not likely to be overly concerned with the risks of pursuing a tight money policy. With his helicopter fueled and ready in case it should be needed, Bernanke’s inclination will be to tilt the balance of risks toward deflation rather than inflation.
First we have to recognize that there is a consensus that deflation is bad. It is a matter of dispute just how bad deflation is. But it is fair to say that those who regard deflation as a potentially healthy process are a small minority. To many, deflation conjures up images of the early 1930s, probably the most unpleasant period in the history of capitalism. There is also dispute – and this is where Bernanke’s speech weighs in – about how hard it would be to end a deflation if such a thing were to materialize. The example of Japan suggests a rather pessimistic prognosis, but Bernanke’s speech makes clear that he thinks more effective anti-deflation policies would have succeeded much sooner in Japan.
As a central banker, one is faced constantly with the problem of balancing risks. The biggest risks, I think most would agree, are, on the one side, deflation, and, on the other side, excessive inflation. The problems associated with high inflation are well known. From a central banker’s point of view, it isn’t really the end of the world, because it is generally acknowledged to be curable. The cure, however, is painful and politically difficult, so most central bankers make diligent efforts to provide more than an ounce of prevention. Deflation, on the other hand, is not generally acknowledged to be curable, so some central bankers might regard it as the end of the world. Anyone who does regard deflation as the end of the world is likely to tilt the balance of risks toward inflation.
Bernanke, it should be abundantly clear, is not such a central banker. Bernanke thinks deflation is a solvable problem, just like inflation, and the solution to the deflation problem is a lot less painful than the solution to the inflation problem. Accordingly, Bernanke is not likely to be overly concerned with the risks of pursuing a tight money policy. With his helicopter fueled and ready in case it should be needed, Bernanke’s inclination will be to tilt the balance of risks toward deflation rather than inflation.
Labels: Bernanke, deflation, economics, inflation, macroeconomics, monetary policy, US economic outlook
9 Comments:
Original and, to me, persuasive take on Bernanke.
On responses to antideflationary measures in Japan and the U.S.: to assume once you have accounted for all differences between two societies in terms of the Usual (Macro) Statistics, you've reached a base template seems more economistic that economic.
Original, and to me, a mistaken take on Bernanke.
Deflation is bad ? Oh, really?
First off, there are two kinds of deflation, one much more pernicious than the other. The first kind is deflation as a consequence of falling demand; this, indeed, can be fatal. Just look at Japan and the Great Depression. This manifests itself in fall in almost all goods in the economy. Which leads to a deflationary spiral and rising real interest rates. And possibly a liquidity trap.
However, the second kind of deflation is good; consider, for instance, the rapid fall in IT prices over the past thirty years ago. Or the fall in the price of light.
You seem to be conflating both issues. Further, Helicopter Ben lost considerable enthusiasm for this his initial plan and largely repudiated it, since FED staff informed him it might be ineffectual. He subsequently became a vocal supporter of Michael Woodfords "precommittment strategy" which was, basically, a price level target. Google "Woodford" and "time dependent monetary policy" and youll see.
Finally, Bernanke is a famous supporter of inflation targeting. You seem to suggest from you conclusion than he's willing to play games, if you will, with the money supply and wont be too bothered about hitting negative inflation if it come to pass. Well.
Buck up, knzn. Buck up. Its nice to have you back, though, picking faults with you again.
My, aren't we all cute and combative.
Let's see -
Price declines in given commodities doesn't constitute "deflation" unless they are extensive enough to cause an average decline across the economy. I'm not sure whether any combination of technological innovations would lead to a benign decline in the CPI, even leaving aside questions of what that should measure - computing power or the price of a bottom-on-the-line pc, to adopt one of your examples.
Deflation in Japan was hardly "fatal", and asset deflation rather than retail price deflation was a more serious problem, especially for a society less oriented toward domestic consumption. Whether a similar level of economic stagnation might indeed be "fatal" in a more combustible society like the U.S. is an interesting question
I don’t mean to suggest that Bernanke is willing to play games. However, there are several issues that arise in the context of a targeting regime. First, how close to zero are you willing to choose the target? Second, how much penalty do you give for going below the target, relative to going above the target? Third, if there is a “toss up” , how do you resolve it subjectively? Someone with the beliefs that Bernanke expressed in his speech will tend to resolve those questions on the hawkish side. His beliefs may have moderated since 2002, but I’m guessing he still leans in that direction.
Regarding whether deflation is a bad thing, I would argue that true deflation (as opposed to declining relative prices when the general price level is stable) is always a bad thing, for three reasons. First, it makes monetary policy more difficult by bringing the zero interest rate floor into play. Second, it distorts investment decisions by making money into a bubble asset. Third, it indicates that the economy is operating below its potential –however high that potential might be. All of these reasons apply even if the source of the deflation is on the supply side. The third reason is of particular importance because it calls into question the whole idea that deflation can have its source on the supply side. Contemporary macroeconomics is rather hostile to the concept of “cost-push inflation.” Shouldn’t it be equally hostile to the concept of “cost-pull deflation”? I would argue in this regard that deflation always represents a policy failure.
酒店喝酒,禮服店,酒店小姐,酒店領檯,便服店,鋼琴酒吧,酒店兼職,酒店兼差,酒店打工,伴唱小姐,暑假打工,酒店上班,酒店兼職,ktv酒店,酒店,酒店公關,酒店兼差,酒店上班,酒店打工,禮服酒店,禮服店,酒店小姐,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店經紀,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,寒假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,寒假打工,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,寒假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,寒假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,寒假打工,酒店小姐,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,寒假打工,酒店小姐,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,酒店傳播,酒店經紀人,酒店,酒店,酒店,酒店 ,禮服店 , 酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,招待所,酒店小姐,酒店兼差,寒假打工,酒店上班,暑假打工,酒店公關,酒店兼職,禮服店 , 酒店小姐 ,酒店經紀 ,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店,酒店,酒店經紀,酒店領檯 ,禮服店 ,酒店小姐 ,酒店經紀 ,酒店兼差,暑假打工, 酒店上班,禮服店 ,酒店小姐 ,酒店經紀 ,酒店兼差,暑假打工, 酒店上班,禮服店 ,酒店小姐 ,酒店經紀 ,酒店兼差,暑假打工, 酒店上班,酒店經紀,酒店經紀,酒店經紀
クレジットカード 現金化
会社設立
キャッシング
ダンボール
アダルトDVD
水 通販
アルカリイオン水
ray ban sunglasses, cheap uggs, uggs, michael kors outlet, ray ban sunglasses, michael kors outlet, prada handbags, ugg boots clearance, oakley sunglasses cheap, longchamp handbags, air max, michael kors outlet, jordan shoes, polo ralph lauren, gucci outlet, christian louboutin, replica watches, louboutin shoes, louis vuitton, ray ban sunglasses, polo ralph lauren outlet, kate spade outlet, burberry outlet, tiffany and co, louis vuitton outlet, louboutin, nike shoes, oakley sunglasses, air max, uggs outlet, cheap oakley sunglasses, tory burch outlet, louis vuitton handbags, ugg outlet, longchamp handbags, louboutin outlet, rolex watches, michael kors outlet, michael kors outlet online sale, burberry outlet, louis vuitton outlet stores, prada outlet, tiffany and co, oakley sunglasses, chanel handbags, longchamp outlet
michael kors, air max pas cher, kate spade handbags, longchamp, true religion outlet, nike free pas cher, ralph lauren, abercrombie and fitch, coach purses, lululemon outlet online, sac burberry, louboutin, air jordan, nike air max, sac longchamp pas cher, timberland, nike roshe run pas cher, coach outlet, nike roshe, air max, true religion jeans, nike free, nike tn, polo ralph lauren, nike blazer, replica handbags, polo lacoste, oakley pas cher, ray ban sunglasses, ray ban pas cher, vanessa bruno, hogan outlet, mulberry, converse pas cher, michael kors outlet, michael kors pas cher, vans pas cher, sac hermes, true religion outlet, coach outlet store online, hollister, true religion jeans, michael kors uk, air max, new balance pas cher, nike air force, sac guess, north face, north face, hollister
ugg, sac louis vuitton, moncler, pandora charms, pandora charms, montre homme, moncler, ugg boots, barbour, moncler, ugg, moncler, supra shoes, louis vuitton uk, barbour, canada goose outlet, marc jacobs, abercrombie, converse, air max, canada goose, moncler, canada goose, juicy couture outlet, wedding dresses, hollister, juicy couture, rolex watches, sac louis vuitton, moncler, canada goose, canada goose, canada goose, moncler outlet, coach outlet store online, toms shoes, gucci, ugg pas cher, moncler, vans, links of london, canada goose uk, pandora jewelry, ugg, ray ban, canada goose jackets, converse shoes, louis vuitton, karen millen, pandora jewelry, sac lancel, louis vuitton
Post a Comment
<< Home