Core of Gold
Using Wolfgang Munchau as an example, Mark Thoma criticizes certain commentators for ignoring “theoretical” arguments for using a core inflation index (rather than headline inflation) to guide monetary policy. I agree with Mark, but in the comments section, I expressed skepticism about our ability to make the point effectively given the complexity of the theories involved. Nonetheless, I’m going try. I won’t go into the actual theory, but I’ll try to make the substance of the case in ordinary English. First I bring Mr. Munchau back to the whipping post:
Though I haven’t made such an explicit suggestion, I might broadly be considered one of those economists, so I guess this is personal. But let’s see. If an index that excludes food, energy, and housing (and maybe a few other things) “no longer bears any relationship to reality,” how about an index that excludes everything except gold bullion? If the former already has no relationship to reality, I suppose the latter must have an inverse relationship to reality. And yet it was just such an index that formed the critical anchor for monetary policy from long before the Common Era until as recently as 35 years ago. (Of course they didn’t call it an index; they just called it “gold.”)
The gold standard certainly had its problems. Along with many other economists, I believe it was partly responsible for the Great Depression. But it would be hard to accuse gold standard advocates of being soft on inflation. In fact, the great advantage of the gold standard was that it gave people a reason to have confidence in the long-term value of money. Even if it had no “relationship to reality,” this gold-only price index was apparently sufficient to solve the main problem that motivates monetary policy’s concern with inflation.
OK, let’s try to solve some of the problems with the gold standard. The overall problem is that a single commodity can have dramatic supply and demand shifts, which produce dramatic price swings relative to other items, and as a result, if money is tied to that commodity, we can experience dramatic swings in the money supply, producing events such as the Great Depression. So instead of just using a single commodity, let’s add some more things to the index: maybe clothing, education, entertainment, communication services, vehicles, recreation, medical care, and a few other things. The resulting index may still have no “relationship to reality,” but if it’s reasonably diverse, it should succeed in minimizing the chance of another Great Depression. The price of gold can fluctuate quite dramatically relative to other items, but the price of gold+clothing+entertainment+communications+etc. – while it may not remain perfectly in sync with the overall price level, and indeed (like gold alone) it may even drift over time – isn’t likely to have dramatic swings over periods of a few years.
Now the question is, where do you stop? Are there certain things you might want to avoid adding to the index? There may be many things, but I would suggest 3 broad categories:
1. Items which experience such dramatic price swings that, even as part of a diverse index, their inclusion might increase the risk of depressions. A certain dark, thick, slippery liquid comes to mind.
2. Items which are over-sensitive to monetary policy. The most extreme example would be short-term bonds. If the Fed were to target an index that included short-term bond prices as a significant component, it would never be able to change interest rates, because any change would immediately produce a dramatic change in the index. This same problem exists, to a lesser degree, with most other assets, such as stocks and (of particular importance) houses.
3. Items which react perversely to monetary policy. If tightening monetary policy casues some items in the index to rise in price, this would make monetary policy more volatile than necessary. This category would generally include items that are extremely capital-intensive, but the particular one that comes to mind is housing services – that is, rent.
I guess it’s about time to make a preposterous suggestion about what to exclude from the core CPI.
Some private sector economists made the preposterous suggestion that housing should also be excluded from the core index. If you go down this route, you end up with a core inflation index that no longer bears any relationship to reality.
Though I haven’t made such an explicit suggestion, I might broadly be considered one of those economists, so I guess this is personal. But let’s see. If an index that excludes food, energy, and housing (and maybe a few other things) “no longer bears any relationship to reality,” how about an index that excludes everything except gold bullion? If the former already has no relationship to reality, I suppose the latter must have an inverse relationship to reality. And yet it was just such an index that formed the critical anchor for monetary policy from long before the Common Era until as recently as 35 years ago. (Of course they didn’t call it an index; they just called it “gold.”)
The gold standard certainly had its problems. Along with many other economists, I believe it was partly responsible for the Great Depression. But it would be hard to accuse gold standard advocates of being soft on inflation. In fact, the great advantage of the gold standard was that it gave people a reason to have confidence in the long-term value of money. Even if it had no “relationship to reality,” this gold-only price index was apparently sufficient to solve the main problem that motivates monetary policy’s concern with inflation.
OK, let’s try to solve some of the problems with the gold standard. The overall problem is that a single commodity can have dramatic supply and demand shifts, which produce dramatic price swings relative to other items, and as a result, if money is tied to that commodity, we can experience dramatic swings in the money supply, producing events such as the Great Depression. So instead of just using a single commodity, let’s add some more things to the index: maybe clothing, education, entertainment, communication services, vehicles, recreation, medical care, and a few other things. The resulting index may still have no “relationship to reality,” but if it’s reasonably diverse, it should succeed in minimizing the chance of another Great Depression. The price of gold can fluctuate quite dramatically relative to other items, but the price of gold+clothing+entertainment+communications+etc. – while it may not remain perfectly in sync with the overall price level, and indeed (like gold alone) it may even drift over time – isn’t likely to have dramatic swings over periods of a few years.
Now the question is, where do you stop? Are there certain things you might want to avoid adding to the index? There may be many things, but I would suggest 3 broad categories:
1. Items which experience such dramatic price swings that, even as part of a diverse index, their inclusion might increase the risk of depressions. A certain dark, thick, slippery liquid comes to mind.
2. Items which are over-sensitive to monetary policy. The most extreme example would be short-term bonds. If the Fed were to target an index that included short-term bond prices as a significant component, it would never be able to change interest rates, because any change would immediately produce a dramatic change in the index. This same problem exists, to a lesser degree, with most other assets, such as stocks and (of particular importance) houses.
3. Items which react perversely to monetary policy. If tightening monetary policy casues some items in the index to rise in price, this would make monetary policy more volatile than necessary. This category would generally include items that are extremely capital-intensive, but the particular one that comes to mind is housing services – that is, rent.
I guess it’s about time to make a preposterous suggestion about what to exclude from the core CPI.
Labels: economics, inflation, macroeconomics
5 Comments:
The original rational for removing housing from the CPI is that it tended to rise when the fed was tightening and produce exactly the impact you are discussing.
before we started using the owners rent measure the CPI included morgages so rising rates caused reported inflation to rise.
Moreover, the housing price measure was not quality adjusted --it was just an average. But in
a rising rate environment builders tend to drop out of the low end of the market first, generating an artificial rise in the average home price.
Both of these generated the tightening causes reported inflation to rise development you are discussing.
Owners equivelent rent was suppose to be an improvement. But is the rise in rents we are now seeing a normal cyclical development that we would expect to see every cycle, or is it a one time event that just happens to coincide with the fed tightening? I'm not sure.
I do think OER was an improvement over the old imputed rent, but since rents are determined in the marketplace, it doesn’t really solve the problem. When imputed rent goes up (assuming one does the imputation correctly), there is ipso facto an incentive to bid up actual rents. So theory says there is a reason to expect this in every cycle. Whether it will always be a big enough effect to be noticeable, as it has been this time around (both on the way down and on the way up), and whether we might normally expect some offsetting factors, are open questions.
酒店喝酒,禮服店,酒店小姐,酒店領檯,便服店,鋼琴酒吧,酒店兼職,酒店兼差,酒店打工,伴唱小姐,暑假打工,酒店上班,酒店兼職,ktv酒店,酒店,酒店公關,酒店兼差,酒店上班,酒店打工,禮服酒店,禮服店,酒店小姐,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店經紀,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,寒假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,寒假打工,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,寒假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,寒假打工,酒店小姐,台北酒店,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,寒假打工,酒店小姐,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,寒假打工,酒店小姐,禮服店 ,酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店小姐,酒店傳播,酒店經紀人,酒店,酒店,酒店,酒店 ,禮服店 , 酒店小姐,酒店經紀,酒店兼差,暑假打工,招待所,酒店小姐,酒店兼差,寒假打工,酒店上班,暑假打工,酒店公關,酒店兼職,禮服店 , 酒店小姐 ,酒店經紀 ,酒店兼差,暑假打工,酒店,酒店,酒店經紀,酒店領檯 ,禮服店 ,酒店小姐 ,酒店經紀 ,酒店兼差,暑假打工, 酒店上班,禮服店 ,酒店小姐 ,酒店經紀 ,酒店兼差,暑假打工, 酒店上班,禮服店 ,酒店小姐 ,酒店經紀 ,酒店兼差,暑假打工, 酒店上班,酒店經紀,酒店經紀,酒店經紀
ray ban sunglasses, cheap uggs, uggs, michael kors outlet, ray ban sunglasses, michael kors outlet, prada handbags, ugg boots clearance, oakley sunglasses cheap, longchamp handbags, air max, michael kors outlet, jordan shoes, polo ralph lauren, gucci outlet, christian louboutin, replica watches, louboutin shoes, louis vuitton, ray ban sunglasses, polo ralph lauren outlet, kate spade outlet, burberry outlet, tiffany and co, louis vuitton outlet, louboutin, nike shoes, oakley sunglasses, air max, uggs outlet, cheap oakley sunglasses, tory burch outlet, louis vuitton handbags, ugg outlet, longchamp handbags, louboutin outlet, rolex watches, michael kors outlet, michael kors outlet online sale, burberry outlet, louis vuitton outlet stores, prada outlet, tiffany and co, oakley sunglasses, chanel handbags, longchamp outlet
michael kors, air max pas cher, kate spade handbags, longchamp, true religion outlet, nike free pas cher, ralph lauren, abercrombie and fitch, coach purses, lululemon outlet online, sac burberry, louboutin, air jordan, nike air max, sac longchamp pas cher, timberland, nike roshe run pas cher, coach outlet, nike roshe, air max, true religion jeans, nike free, nike tn, polo ralph lauren, nike blazer, replica handbags, polo lacoste, oakley pas cher, ray ban sunglasses, ray ban pas cher, vanessa bruno, hogan outlet, mulberry, converse pas cher, michael kors outlet, michael kors pas cher, vans pas cher, sac hermes, true religion outlet, coach outlet store online, hollister, true religion jeans, michael kors uk, air max, new balance pas cher, nike air force, sac guess, north face, north face, hollister
Post a Comment
<< Home